Land Prices and New Housing

Some commentators argue that even if cities allow housing supply to expand, more permissive zoning will cause land prices to increase, causing rents to rise rather than fall. This post disagrees.

3 minute read

March 28, 2017, 2:00 PM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


facades of victorian style residences in San Francisco

idleformat / flickr

The law of supply and demand suggests that if zoning becomes less restrictive, the supply of housing will expand, causing housing to become less expensive. Yet some commentators argue that new supply will not be helpful, because new housing leads to higher land prices. They reason as follows: if you can build more houses on parcel X, you can get more income from that parcel. If you can get more income from parcel X, the market value of parcel X will rise. In turn, future developers will pass the higher cost of land on to homebuyers or renters.

I find this argument unpersuasive for a variety of reasons. First, the argument leads to preposterous results. If it is really the case that new housing increases prices, then prohibiting new housing would lower prices. And if prohibiting new housing lowers price, downzoning (or better yet, demolishing the existing housing supply) would lower prices even more—obviously an absurd result. In fact, aggressive downzoning has been tried in Los Angeles. In 1960, the city was zoned to support 10 million people. By contrast, today the city is zoned for roughly its current population, which means that almost any new construction will require a rezoning. Did housing prices fall? No. In fact, rents, adjusted for inflation, have risen by 55 percent, while median renter income has grown by only 13 percent. Nor did land prices fall. Land values have increased more rapidly than home prices, from just over $86,229 per house in 1984 to $483,692 in 2014.*

Second, as a matter of theory, increased land values need not lead to increased rents: if my parcel was worth $100,000 but now is worth $200,000, I can build one $200,000 unit on my land—but I can also build two $100,000 units, or increase the housing supply by building multiple units costing less than $100,000. As long as zoning does not limit housing supply, land prices may affect the size and height of housing units rather than the price of those units.

Third, the argument would make more sense if land prices were as stable as rents, because if land prices rose and fell rapidly while rents did not, it would appear that the land price/rent link is not very strong. In fact, land prices are quite volatile: in metropolitan New York City metro area, the land price (apparently per house) swung from $99,916 at the end of 1996 to $418,592 at the end of 2006, down to under $225,000 in early 2012, and up to $250,187 in 2014.* Rent was far less volatile, generally increasing over time.  Thus, it appears that the link between land prices and rents is modest. 

Fourth, if new housing caused rents to increase, the regions that allowed the most new housing would be the regions with the highest rents. But permissive regions such as Dallas and Houston often have pretty low housing prices. (See here for a larger dataset.)

Finally, if increased supply caused rents to increase, rents would never go down unless a city aggressively reduced the housing supply. But in fact this has not been the case; over the past year, rents have started to go down even in some pricey metro areas- even in New York. (By an odd coincidence, construction seems to have increased). 

*All data on land and home prices comes from the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy database.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is a professor at Touro University, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

portrait of professional woman

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching. Mary G., Urban Planner

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching.

Mary G., Urban Planner

Get top-rated, practical training

Red 1972 Ford Pinto with black racing stripes on display with man sitting in driver's seat.

Analysis: Cybertruck Fatality Rate Far Exceeds That of Ford Pinto

The Tesla Cybertruck was recalled seven times last year.

July 2, 2025 - Mother Jones

Close-up of park ranger in green jacket and khaki hat looking out at Bryce Canyon National Park red rock formations.

National Parks Layoffs Will Cause Communities to Lose Billions

Thousands of essential park workers were laid off this week, just before the busy spring break season.

February 18, 2025 - National Parks Traveler

Paved walking path next to canal in The Woodlands, Texas with office buildings in background.

Retro-silient?: America’s First “Eco-burb,” The Woodlands Turns 50

A master-planned community north of Houston offers lessons on green infrastructure and resilient design, but falls short of its founder’s lofty affordability and walkability goals.

February 19, 2025 - Greg Flisram

Screenshot of shade map of Buffalo, New York with legend.

Test News Post 1

This is a summary

0 seconds ago - 2TheAdvocate.com

Red 1972 Ford Pinto with black racing stripes on display with man sitting in driver's seat.

Analysis: Cybertruck Fatality Rate Far Exceeds That of Ford Pinto

The Tesla Cybertruck was recalled seven times last year.

18 minutes ago - Mother Jones

test alt text

Test News Headline 46

Test for the image on the front page.

March 5 - Cleantech blog